From NewGeography, via Ron Richings:
.
Urbanists Need to Face the Full Implications of Peak Car
.
As traffic levels decline nationally in defiance of the usual state DOT forecasts projecting major increases, a number of commentators have claimed that we’ve reached “peak car” – the point at which the seemingly inexorable rise in vehicle miles traveled in America finally comes to an end. But while this has been celebrated, with some justification in the urbanist world as vitiating plans for more roads, the implications for public policy haven’t been fully faced up to.
Indeed, the “peak car” is antithetical to the reigning urbanist paradigm of highways known as “induced demand.” Induced demand is Say’s Law for roads: supply of lanes creates its own demand by drivers to fill them. Hence building more roads to reduce congestion is pointless. But if we’ve really reached peak car, maybe we really can build our way out of congestion after all.
Traffic levels have stabilized or even fallen in recent years. According to analysis by economist Doug Short featured in Streetsblog, aggregate auto travel peaked on a per capita basis in 2005 and has fallen since. Per capita traffic levels are now back to 1994 levels, a two decade rollback in traffic increases. …
This data is complemented by a slew of recent stories about the poor financial performance of toll roads, resulting in part from traffic falling far below projections. For example, the concessionaire operating the Indiana Toll Road recently went bankrupt. Streetsblog reported that while projections forecasted traffic level increase of 22% in the first seven years, traffic actually fell 11% in the first eight.
Recent traffic declines are a reversal of a long running trend of Vehicle Miles Traveled (VMT) increases at above growth in population. Some of this is no doubt due to the poor macro-economy. But there are reasons to believe we may be in a new era of traffic growth or lack thereof. Many of the trends that drove high growth have largely been played out: household size declines, suburbanization, the entry of women into the workforce, one car per driver, etc. That’s not to say these will necessarily reverse. But we’ve reached the point of diminishing returns in terms of how many more women, for example, will join the labor force given that there’s already 57% female participation and their labor force participation rate is projected to decline in the future. …
So the idea that we need to build fewer roads than we thought is sound. But less attention has been paid to the flip side implications of this. To repeat, the induced demand theory says that there is a more or less infinite supply of traffic, thus any new roadway capacity will be used up shortly, leaving congestion as bad as the status quo ante.
Despite peak car, articles touting induced demand as a reason not to build roads continue unabated, including recent ones in Wired (“What’s Up With That: Building Bigger Roads Actually Makes Traffic Worse”) and Vox (“The ‘fundamental rule’ of traffic: building new roads just makes people drive more”). In a world of peak car, where traffic levels are flat to declining on a per capita basis, induced demand no longer holds court, certainly not to the level claimed by those who believe it’s pointless to build roads.
In fact, what peak car means is that while speculative projects may be dubious, there many be good reasons now to build projects designed to alleviate already exiting congestion. Places like Los Angeles remain chronically congested, which has great economic and social consequences, not the least of which is the value of untold hours lost sitting in traffic. While individual projects there might indeed be boondoggles, maybe it’s worth building some of the planned freeway expansions there in light of peak car. In short, in some cases peak car strengthens the argument for building or expanding roads.
On the other hands, many of the regional development plans designed to promote compact central city development and transit may be predicated on an analysis that assumes large future traffic increases in a “business as usual” scenario. Not just highways but all aspects of regional planning are dependent on traffic forecasts. That’s not to say that such plans are necessarily wrong, but clearly revised traffic reality needs to be reflected in all plans, not just highway building ones.
It’s not clear how this will all play out, but urbanists and policy makers of all stripes need to think about the full implications of peak car. At a minimum, the traditional “you can’t build your way out of congestion” rhetoric should be supplanted, at least in most areas, by a more nuanced approach that neither overestimates demand, nor ignores the problems caused by rapid growth in some regions and pockets of congestion in others.
Aaron M. Renn is an independent writer on urban affairs and the founder of Telestrian, a data analysis and mapping tool. He writes at The Urbanophile.
This ignores many factors including the simple one of land. Let’s say we agree with this argument, ok, where do you put all this new highway? Also ignores social, environmental, etc…
With a growing population many urban areas will have car use for many more decades. Likely km driven per resident will on average decline, it total it might still be flat or slightly rising as many cities grow by 2-3% per year due to immigration, jobs, folks moving from depressed rural areas and more babies. Cares might get smaller, and/or electric, but the individual vehicle, be it a bike, a scooter, an oversized golf cart or an e-SUV will be with us deep into the next century, and with Uber-like technologies we might even have more than 1 person on average in it.
Perhaps even the left wing mayors of Burnaby or Vancouver will eventually understand the benefits here.
So what should the left wing mayors do? Build more highways? How does that help?
Allow Uber. Amend the taxi aka “commercial passenger transportation” by-laws. Allow more people per car for pennies per km. That would ease congestion on the highway and in the public transit system.
Also: toll roads and build more subways, by raising property taxes, and by not asking the provinces and the federal government for those $s !
Also: lower commercial taxes to induce job creation, as opposed to a residential suburb only.
So you weren’t talking benefits of highways in a post about highways. ok…
The concept of Induced Demand is a commonly-misunderstood and misused. It is also a misnomer, and I think this is the reason for your thinking that it is incompatible with the Peak Car phenomenon. It is not.
Demand isn’t induced by building more roads and demand is certainly not infinite. Building more capacity simply lowers the cost of driving (and perception of cost), for a while, in terms of time and perceived convenience. You’ve increased the supply of something which reduces its cost, and allows more people to choose to access it. However, there will always be limits on what different people can afford or are willing to pay.
Our over-supply of road and highway space dedicated to private vehicles has made driving a relatively ‘cheap’ modal option, but still obviously not cheap enough for many, given the trade-off’s involved in longer commuting times and vehicle costs. There is a real correlation between the supply we produce (road capacity) and the modal choices people make. All Peak Car shows is that along with other economic factors at play, there is a diminishing return on increases to that supply. You still can’t build your way out of congestion.
I think a bit of an oversimplification, and not applicable to the environs around Vancouver where rapid population growth trumps waning car demand. I doubt that Surrey has reached peak car, even if Vancouver has.
Interesting how many urban geographers really don’t have a good grasp of economics. I see it time and again in articles such as these. The lack of understanding of the nuances of supply and demand causes them to reach conclusions that really end up missing the mark.
Out at UBC it’s pretty clear that peak car was reached a long time ago. Despite big increases of students, faculty, staff and residents. Since 1997 daily traffic from and to UBC has declined by about 15,000 cars or over 20%. http://bikewalkubc.org/moti/technical#Traffic
It would be interesting to see exactly what caused the decline. Looking at the graph, the introduction of the UPass does not seem to have a clear impact on the number of motor vehicles. The 2001 transit strike had a clear impact though. Much of the underlying dynamics is probably due to partial elimination of the parking subsidy at UBC, with most parking being structured now leading to higher capital and maintenance costs being passed on to users.
There is still lots of room for eliminating the remaining parking subsidy, land is still given for free for parking (as opposed to housing).
You can bet that UBC is having to increase salaries to compensate for the amount they charge faculty for parking. What one hand takes the other hand gives.
@Jens
I wouldn’t be so quick to dismiss U-Pass. Draw a best fit straight line through the 1998-2003 data and it’s clear that no decline was occurring.
But U-Pass didn’t arrive in a vacuum at UBC. It’s introduction coincided with the decommissioning of hectares of inexpensive surface parking. Driving to school got significantly more expensive or inconvenient at exactly the same time that transit got significantly cheaper. Additionally UBC used some of the old parking lots to build new student housing, further reducing the number of people driving to school. That was followed by even more parking price increases and the construction of more and more housing, both subsidized student spaces and market housing that might appeal to faculty. The message “don’t drive here, live here instead” was delivered loud and clear.
That makes sense, though, doesn’t it ? UBC creates more revenue, people drive less and land gets used for better purposes than surface parking.
Surface parking must be one of the worst land uses out there. Strange to me that surface parking is free in far too many places. This is green ? This is good land use ?
@David, I would love to see some detailed analysis what caused the decline in traffic. My money is still on the parking fees effectively acting as a road toll on the UBCS access routes.
As to the “message”, I would say it’s more like “we still prefer you drive here and not live here, just not as much as we used to.”
After all, UBC still subsidizes parking more than (faculty and student) housing. But they have come a long way in reducing the parking subsidy.
since we lived here for five years we have noted an INCREASE in traffic as more folks now live here, both residents like you and me and also students. more folks traveling back and forth, visiting friends, ordering pizza, etc … likely down from the car crazy pre UPass 1980’s but UP from 2008 or so !
Except that the data shows there is a clear decrease since 2008…. By about 10%.
most recent data is from when ?
NOT evidenced by traffic on Wesbrook or Chancellor Blvd
Most recent data from fall 2013. Just look at the graph.
Don’t know about Wesbrook Mall, but Chancellor has seen pretty much the same decrease as overall traffic. About 10% since 2008. http://bikewalkubc.org/moti/chancellor#Traffic
Correct me if I’m wrong but aren’t new car registrations in the City of Vancouver still climbing? Per capita may be down but the absolute number of cars in the city, let alone metro, continues to climb.
The absolute number of cars registered in the City of Vancouver is indeed growing. In absolute numbers, “peak car” has not yet arrived in Vancouver.
There’s an interesting pattern to the vehicle registrations added each year, though:
http://postimg.org/image/wklxva1r1/
(I hope that image link works!)
So, maybe it’s not so much that more car lanes induce more motor vehicle usage, but that lack of other options usually associated with adding more car lanes forces people to drive more than they naturally would. Traditionally when more motor lanes or roads are introduced space for other modes are not included. This signals to people what is expected of them in regards to travel.
A good example is the Gateway project. A lot of money spent and homes disrupted but still is monomodal. They could have had light rail in the centre meridian, they could have included AAA cycle routes but they didn’t.
Is the gateway project the South Fraser Perimeter Road from Tsawwassen to Langley ?
It is designed primarily for trucks, secondary for cars .. cyclists and train likely makes no sense here as it goes primarily though industrial areas along Fraser River. Due to opposition in Vancouver and Burnaby, the “Vancouver” harbours are actually primarily on the Fraser River, as attested to by the Massey bridge and removal of Massey Tunnel to dredge the Fraser deeper to allow bigger container ships. Vancouver’s and Burnaby’s loss in New West’s, Richmond’s and Surrey’s gain, relegating Vancouver and Burnaby to more of a bedroom/suburb status.
The bigger issue is the lack of a train track on the 10 lane Port Mann Bridge to connect Fraser Valley towns to Vancouver. That was indeed a grave error. This new bridge does have a cycling lane on the east side, though, to be opened in 2015: http://www.pmh1project.com/transportation-choices/cycling-pedestrians/Pages/default.aspx
I’ve been contemplating this, and have been wondering if peak car is actually an artifact of reduced road supply in select larger cities – freeway removals, reallocating space to bicycles and dedicated transit lanes – as well as new road/bridge projects increasingly being toll-funded. Induced demand relies on no monetary cost to use the road, so empty toll roads don’t contradict it in any way.